Archive for the ‘Economics’ Category

Diverging Employment Indices and Politics

Wednesday, August 11th, 2004

When President Jimmy Carter was running against President Gerald Ford in 1976, the economy was by most standards doing very poorly, and Carter wanted to focus on this condition to make his case for the presidency. In the process, he coined the term “misery index.” Typically, unemployment and inflation tend to run in counter cycles with one running higher, while the other runs lower. In the 1970’s, we suffered under both high inflation and high unemployment and the sum of the two is what Carter defined as the misery index. Carter’s new index had a saliency because it was easy to understand and it reflected the sad concurrent economic experience of most people.

Carter inherited an historically high misery index in the low teens from Ford, but managed to steer the economy into a misery index over twenty before handing over to President Reagan an economy at a misery index in the high teens. The misery index plummeted thoughout Reagan’s two terms. Reagan’s second term ended at the post-war average of ten for the misery index. We have either been just a little over ten or substantially below that figure since then. Indeed, the first four years of George W. Bush’s Administration had a lower misery index than Clinton’s first four years.

The current misery index is about where it was when Bush took office despite an inherited recession and the attacks of September 11. The current inflation rate of about one percentage point less than is less than the post-war mean of 4.4% and the current unemployment rate of 5.5% is less than the post-war average of 6.4%

Under these conditions, the traditional misery index was useless as a political bludgeon to go after Bush. Hence, Democratic presidential candidate John Kerry yielded to the temptation to conjure up a new misery index. Kerry’s index was so contorted and convoluted that it made Jimmy Carter’s record of double digit inflation and double digit unemployment (and should we add double-digit interest rates) appear to be better than our current, comparatively benign conditions. Not even Democratic partisans bought into the index because it was more likely to highlight Kerry’s intellectual dishonesty than it was to persuade people that Carter’s economic experience of the 1970’s was to be preferred. Voters were not convinced in 1980 that the economy was doing well when they dumped Carter in a landslide and they were not likely to be convinced that conditions are worse now.

While the employment rate, the traditional measure of unemployment, has been steadily declining, Democrats reverted to citing to everyone who would listen, the payroll survey numbers. This employment index shows a net decrease of 1.1 million jobs since Bush assumed office. Now, in fairness the peak in employment in the payroll survey data came in late 2000 and the downward trend began before Bush took office. Indeed, during the first year of the Bush term, which included not only an inherited recession but the September 11 attacks the total employment as measured by the payroll survey dropped by 1.7 million. The employment bottomed out in August 2003. With fits and starts, the payroll employment survey indicates that 1.5 million jobs have been added in the last year.

However, the payroll survey is not the only measure of employment published by the Bureau of Labor Statistics. The Bureau also computes an employment index based on household surveys. They literally call 60,000 households and ask them if they are employed. This last month, the payroll survey showed just a 32,000 increase in employment, while the household survey showed a 600,000 person employment increase. Indeed, this latter measure has show a significant increase of 1.8 million in total employment over the last four years. This represents an over 3 million person disparity between the two employment indices. This clearly represents more than statistical fluctuations between the two surveys. Thise recent divergence between the surveys has puzzled economists.

Economists have generally preferred to use the payroll survey because the sample size (400,000) is larger, reducing the month-to-month sampling variability and the two surveys have tracked reasonably well in the past. However, there is more to accuracy than statistical sampling errors. Part of the problem may be associated with the fact that the press has been focusing primarily on the preliminary rather than revised monthly numbers. The payroll survey is often revised months even years later. These revisions have often been dramatic. The payroll employment survey for 1992 was adjusted so many times in the following two years that 1992 (the last recovery) went from showing a net job loss to a net gain. Hence, the payroll survey is a much better retrospective tool than when considered in “real-time.”

It is also well known that certain corrections have to be made to the payroll survey data. If during a single month a person moves from one job to another, that employee is counted twice. This will tend to inflate the payroll survey data. Attempts are made to adjust for this. However, if during different parts of the business cycle, employed people are more or less apt to switch jobs than average, it can introduce biases in the survey. In addition, self employment and employment in new firms is often missed in the preliminary payroll survey measurements, but caught in the household survey. However, unemployed people may report themselves a “self-employed” perhaps out of denial.

All these are rather technical issues and there is not doubt that the Bureau of Labor Statistics does a professional and credible job attempting to capture snapshots of the state of the dynamic and diverse economy. However, the question must be asked why an esoteric and heretofore little known statistic has gained such prominence. One cannot blame Democrats for trying to use it because, of the three employment measures: the employment rate, the payroll survey, and the household survey, the payroll survery was the single most politically exploitable. Partisans often pick and choose indices to suit their purposes. However, one can blame the press for grasping on to this particular index, downplaying the more traditional unemployment rate without a clear reason why.

At the very least, attention should have been given the different measures of employment and their respective advantages and disadvantages. These indices must be considered in the light of other measures like the number of unemployment claims, withholding tax receipts, and indices of real earnings. One wishes that the national media would devote the same level of professionalism to covering economic statistics as the Bureau of Labor Statistics exhibits in their creation and maintenance. In the end of course, reporting on the economy can only effect perceptions at the margins. Though the margins can be important in close elections, by-and-large, people vote based on their personal economic experiences not on indices.

References

  1. US Bureau of Labor Statistics.
  2. Kane, T., Diverging Employment Data, The Heritage Foundation, March 4, 2004.

Is the Dow Jones Industrial Average Where It Ought to Be?

Wednesday, October 2nd, 2002

In the nineteenth century, investing in publicly traded stocks was properly considered a highly speculative enterprise. There was little reliable independent information and businesses tended to hide bad economic news. With the collapse of Enron and WorldCom, we have recently become reacquainted with this behavior. Nineteenth century investors wisely preferred to invest in corporate bonds that promised regular payments backed by real collateral. Information about the stock values of companies was so sparse and unreliable that it was often impossible to assess the current general health of business stocks.

In stepped journalists Charles Dow and Edward D. Jones. In 1882, they formed Dow, Jones, and Company. The company started publishing subscription newsletters with business information. The newsletter eventually evolved into the now famous Wall Street Journal. In 1884, they created the Dow Jones Industrial Average as a measure of general stock market performance. The original index consisted of only 11 companies, including nine railroads. There was a certain logic in heavily weighting railroads. Not only were railroads large industrial enterprises but the economic performance of railroads also indirectly reflected the fortunes of other companies that shipped via railroads.

Over time, the list of companies grew and changed radically. Presently 30 are included in the index. Many of them like Boeing, Hewlett Packard, International Business Machines, and Intel reflect the changing nature of the economy in the past one hundred years. Now there are many more market indices. The Standard and Poor’s 500 represents the collective performance of 500 of the countries biggest companies. The Wilshire 5000 is so large that it measures essentially the returns of almost all publicly traded US companies.

The present value of the Dow Jones Industrial Average is that it provides an exceptionally long time series of economic performance. Whereas the Dow began in the nineteenth century, the Wilshire 5000 began in only 1974. Hence, even though the Dow may be a narrow and imperfect index, it is the best we have to monitor and study long-term variations in stock performance.

Figure 1 is a log plot of the Dow Jones Industrial average since its inception. The most conspicuous feature of the time series is its relentless growth. There is a clear persistent dip in the index during the Great Depression in the 1930s. However, decade-in-and-decade-out the stock market and the Dow yield strong positive returns. Plotting the index on a log graph emphasizes the variations. If plotted on a linear scale, the general upward movement in value would be ever more conspicuous.
This increase has been so persistent and the rise from January 1980 to January 2000, when the market peaked at 11,700, was so rapid that some have become overly optimistic. In 1999, James Glassman and Kevin Hassett suggested that people now realized that in the long run stocks provide larger and more reliable returns than other investments. This new understanding would drive up prices. Glassman and Hassett predicted that, “Stocks are now, we believe, in the midst of a one-time-only rise to much higher ground — to the neighborhood of 36,000 for the Dow Jones Industrial Average. After they complete this historic ascent, owning them will still be profitable but the returns will decline.” Given that the Dow is now below 8,000, it does not seem likely that we will see the Dow at 36,000 any time soon. The recent plunge in the market has devastated the retirement plans of many and a subtle fear is becoming palpable.

While the effects of the decreases in stock values since 2000 are very real, a closer examination offers modest room for hope. Figure 2 is a log plot of the Dow Jones Industrial Average from 1980 to the present. From 1980 to about 1995, the values of the stock market increased at a rate of over 10% per year. Then in 1996, the stock market literally exploded upward in what Federal Reserve Chairman Alan Greenspan then described as a fit of “irrational exuberance.” The straight line drawn in Figure 2 shows the increase in the Dow if it had simply followed the same healthy growth rate it had experienced from 1980 to 1995. The stock market would be approximately where it is right down. Holders of stocks would not be appreciably richer, but they would certainly feel less anxious.

Markets are never sufficiently disciplined or wise to grow along easily predictable straight lines. Markets that overshoot the long-term growth rate will likely undershoot that same growth rate for a while. The pain is not over. Nonetheless, the fact that the Dow is about where we might expect it to be given its long-term growth rate offers a least a small ray of comfort for those who have lost many paper profits over the last few years. Or perhaps this is just “whistling past the graveyard.”

Wealth and the Environment

Sunday, July 14th, 2002

Notwithstanding Mark Twain’s solemn advice to, “Get your facts first, and then you can distort them as much as you please. (Facts are stubborn, but statistics are more pliable.)” allow me to dangle an illuminating graph for your consideration. The variables on the graph shown in Figure 1 require a modest amount of explanation, but the concept behind them is powerful. The graph is borrowed from The Skeptical Environmentalist by Bjorn Lomborg (Page 33). The source for the data in the graph is the World Economic Forum of the Yale Center for Environmental Law and Policy and the World Bank.

envi_v_ppp1.gif
Figure 1: Environmental Stability versus GDP. (From The Skeptical Environmentalist by Bjorn Lomborg, Page 33.)

The horizontal axis represents per capita Gross Domestic Product (GDP) in units of Purchasing Power Parity (PPP) dollars for different countries. This is a mouthful of alliteration describing a normalized measure of per capita productive wealth production. It is a complex matter to compare wealth in different countries. The PPP dollar is an attempt to reduce this complexity to a single value. In short, regardless of what a particular product or service — a gallon of milk, a loaf of bread, a train ride, or a Big Mac — costs in local currency, it should cost the same in PPP dollars. PPP dollars are a best effort at measuring relative wealth in different economies using different currencies. Just think of the horizontal axis as the rate of per capita wealth generation.

The vertical axis is an environmental sustainability index. It is a combination of various measures of the environmental status including pollution of the air and water. The larger the value, the better off the country is environmentally.

There is certainly wide variability from country to country, but the implication of Figure 1 is not only clear, but also runs counter to the conventional wisdom of the age. The greater the per capita wealth of a country, the greater is the sustainability of its environment. Not only is productive capacity not inimical to a clean environment, it is positively correlated to it. Of course, correlation is not the same as causality. Nonetheless, it is clear that the large and complex web of economic, political, and social factors that contribute to high levels of economic growth are also associated with clean environments.

Figure 1 should remind those on the Right that there might be money to be made from environmental friendliness. But the Right has long recognized that all resources, including wealth are finite, and that priorities in environment must be weighed against costs.

The Left by contrast has more to learn. It has raised environmentalism to a religious sentiment in the hopes that the issue could be used as leverage to increase public supervision of the economy. Except for those of a Left-wing anti-globalization temperament whose minds have long ago been constipated by the lack of intellectual fiber, Figure 1 demonstrates that an automatic Luddite opposition to economic growth is irrational and counterproductive. Having a clean environment is an important value and it seems that one way to achieve it is to maintain a robust growing economy.

Pondering the Infinite

Sunday, April 28th, 2002

Pondering the infinite is an activity usually relegated to undergraduate philosophy students, particularly in their sophomore year. Physicists often spend their time reducing physical phenomena that are for all practical purposes, like the size of the universe, infinite to comprehensible descriptions. Mathematicians are perhaps the most facile in dealing with and manipulating concepts of infinity. For a mathematician, it is a simple matter to specify a mathematical surface that is infinite in area, but encloses a finite volume. In other words, mathematicians can conceive of a shape that one could fill with paint, but not paint. It is not until recently, that people in computer sciences have considered quantities and qualities, which if formally finite, may prove to be practically infinite.

In 1965, Gordon Moore, one of the founders of Intel, extrapolated from the fact that the number of transistors on a integrated circuit grew from one in 1959, to 32 in 1964, to 64 in 1965 that transistor density was doubling every 18 to 24 months. This is the narrow statement of Moore’s Law. The more general statement of Moore’s Law is that computer computing power doubles every 18 to 24 months.

The latter formulation of Moore’s law has been given more depth by MIT-educated computer scientist, entrepreneur and writer Ray Kurzweil. He has tracked back the growth of computer power from electromagnetic punch card calculators used in the 1890 census to Pentium 4 processors that have 42 million transistors. Kurzweil foresees accelerating increases in computer power past physical limits of silicon-based devices as manufactures employ more exotic bio-chemical technologies.

Much thought has been given to whether Moore’s Law can really exceed limits posed by silicon-based technology and the ever-increasing capital costs required to construct chip-manufacturing plants. Additional consideration has been given as to what this increased computer power can be used for. Kurzweil is not shy about predicting a future with machines that are more intelligent than humans and computer implants interfaced to human minds. While increases in computer capacity has proven to be more persistent in time that anyone has a right to expect, predictions about the future abilities of artificial intelligence have a notorious record of over optimism.

What has not received much thought is the rapid increase in data storage. Writing in American Scientist, Brian Hayes explains how recent changes in technology are actually increasing rate of growth is disk storage. A large disk on a personal computer is about 120 GBytes. Technologies in the laboratory presently achieve storage densities equivalent to disks with 400 GBytes of storage.

At the present rate of increase, personal computer disks will reach 120 Terabytes (120,000 GBytes) in size in ten years. Even if the growth rate decreases by 60 percent, the 120 TByte level will be reached in 15 years. What are we to do with this storage capability? Is natural American acquisitiveness sufficiently great to use of this space.

Recently MP3 digtial music files have been filling disks, especially in college dorms. However, as Hayes points out, if you put enough music to listen to different songs 24 hours a day for an 80 year lifetime you barely fill a third of a 120 TByte disk disk. Even this assumes that storage technology would remain fixed over the 80-year lifetime.

Digital photographs are a new source of data filling up disks. Assuming each such photograph require 1 MByte of storage and assuming a itchy shutter finger producing 100 photographs a day — certainly a well-documented life — less than 3% of the 120 TBytes would be filled.

Fundamentally, storage of video is the only data source likely to fill 120 Tbyte disks. Even so, with growth beyond 120 TBytes over our lifetimes, we likely face the prospect of being able to store more data than we have. It is roughly comparable to having an attic that is growing so fast that we cannot fill it fast enough.

It seems that if we are having problems filling up new disks over a lifetime, the only solution is to increase lifetimes.

  • Fixmer, Rob, “Internet Insight, Moore’s Law and Order,” Eweek, April 15, 2002.
  • Hayes, Brian, “Terabyte Territory,” American Scientist, 90, 212-216, May-June, 2002.

When Chapter 11 Does Not Mean Bankruptcy

Sunday, February 10th, 2002

Within the United States, free trade works to the benefit of all. Goods and services pass easily between Pennsylvania and Maryland, between California and Nevada, between Georgia and Florida. One reason internal US trade works is that the rule of law exists. If a fraudulent transaction takes place in one state, there is a reasonable chance that someone in another state can achieve effective recourse in the courts. In addition, although states can enact legislation locally, the federal government retains the exclusive right to regulate interstate commerce. Indeed, it was the impediments to free trade between states under the Articles of Confederation that motivated the writers of the Constitution to prohibit the states from regulating interstate commerce.

The presence of barriers to international commerce had been an impediment to prosperity in Europe. The rise of the European Union represents a recognition of this. Europe is on a rapid track to full economic integration, now that these countries largely share a common currency.

The North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) is an attempt to largely achieve the benefits of free trade between the United States, Canada, and Mexico. The increase in trade and prosperity following the enactment of the agreement is a testimony to the benefits of free trade. There was not the great “sucking sound” of jobs being vacuumed out of the United States predicted by some.

Nonetheless, Bill Moyers in the PBS program Now: Trading Democracy focuses on what may turn out to be an important if not fatal flaw in the agreement. Whereas most corporations would like to avoid Chapter 11 when it refers to bankruptcy, some that invest in foreign countries are trying exploit Chapter 11 of NAFTA. The offending section Chapter reads:

“No Party may directly or indirectly nationalize or expropriate an investment of an investor of another Party in its territory or take a measure tantamount to nationalization or expropriation of such an investment (“expropriation”), except: (a) for a public purpose; (b) on a nondiscriminatory basis; (c) in accordance with due process of law and Article 1105(1); and (d) on payment of compensation….”

Actually, the provision seems to make sense. If one wants to encourage investment, the investors must be confident that their investments will not be arbitrarily seized. The penalty for the expropriation is payment of fair market compensation.

The problem that Moyers focuses on in his special is potential overly broad interpretation of the “tantamount to expropriation” clause. Apparently, California passed an environmental regulation limiting the chemical additive MTBE in gasoline. The chemical had found its way into ground water and there are serious questions about the long-term health consequences of human exposure to MTBE. The Canadian company, Methanex is a major manufacturor of MTBE. It is now suing California under Chapter 11 of NAFTA. Methanex is submitting to an arbitration tribunal set up as part of NAFTA a request for nearly $1 billion in compensation for an act that is “tantamount to nationalization or expropriation.”

Essentially, the thesis of Moyers Special is that the corporations will be able to use the Chapter 11 provision of NAFTA to assert that any government action that might reduce profits is equivalent to expropriation. While such creative interpretations are possible by the tribunal, they are not likely to survive long. Either the tribunal’s rulings will be consistently reasonable or the treaty will be re-negotiated.

The clause cited above specifically gives governments the right to regulate so long as the regulation is directed to a “public purpose” and “nondiscriminator.” Indeed, later in the NAFTA agreement, environmental regulations are specifically allowed.

“Nothing in this Chapter shall be construed to prevent a Party from adopting, maintaining or enforcing any measure otherwise consistent with this Chapter that it considers appropriate to ensure that investment activity in its territory is undertaken in a manner sensitive to environmental concerns.”

It is always possible for creative lawyers to conjure up new interpretations of a law inconsistent with the original understanding of those who drafted the legislation. Indeed, that is the goal of much of modern interpretation of Constitutional law. It is the purpose of courts and other tribunals to dismiss interpretations that are too expansive. It was disappointing that Moyers did not discuss in greater details the other provisions of Chapter 11 relating to environmental regulation.

What was amusing was to see in the Now program, the solemn hand wringing of William Greider of the Liberal Nation magazine and Martin Wagner of Earthjustice Legal Defense Fund concerned about national sovereignty. I suspect that neither would shed a tear about national sovereignty if international environment agreements were used to compel compliance to stricter environmental regulations even if they US cost jobs and trumped local or national decisions.

There are very important and legitimate concerns about limitations of sovereignty in any international agreement. It is nice to see the Left learn such a concern. Possible unreasonable interpretations of NAFTA ought to be scrutinized. Nonetheless, it does seem that a dispassionate reading of the entire NAFTA agreement would preclude the problems cited in the Moyers special. If, however, the NAFTA tribunal makes consistently unreasonable or expansive interpretations, NAFTA should be reconsidered. The problem that Moyers focuses on is not a problem with the concept of free trade, but in the details in implementing a free trade protocol in the age of creative interpretation of the law.

Never Never Land

Sunday, August 26th, 2001

It often seems that one should look over one’s shoulder in Washington, DC and search for Tinkerbell. Politicians seem to exist in Never Never Land, where little boys always play games and never grow up. At this moment, the economy is limping along at low growth levels while Democrats and Republicans argue about how to keep federal surpluses at historic highs. The total debt is rapidly decreasing, deflating the economy so much that successive cuts in the Federal Reserve rate have not yet restored robust economic growth.What few people realize is that even if the annual federal deficit is nominally zero and the total federal debt does not increase in a particular year, inflation and growth conspire to reduce real debt load. A zero deficit is deflationary and a modest deficit can be neutral.

During the late 1970s, inflation was so high that real debt was rapidly decreasing the debt load even while the country ran a nominally high yearly deficit. That explains how during the Carter-years we experienced a large nominal deficit with a sluggish economy suffering high unemployment. The lowest federal debt load in the post World War II era occurred in 1979, at a time when inflation was over 11 percent. Presently, total federal debt load is rapidly decreasing and we should take care in imposing substantially more deflationary pressure on the economy. Even we if had no growth, inflation would convert a surplus into a two to three percent decrease in the real debt load.

A Conservative wit once remarked that America has two parties the “stupid” party (Republicans) and the “evil’ party (Democrats). Apparently when both Republicans and Democrats agree on something, the policy is likely to be both stupid and evil. Thus in February of this year, Congress passed the Social Security and Medicare Lock-Box Act of 2001 by a bi-partisan vote of 407-2.

Of course the lock box is a fiction. Excess funds received from Social Security can do three possible things. They can fund more current spending, allow for tax reductions, or reduce the total federal debt. Republicans, for their part, hope that the budget discipline imposed by keeping the federal total surplus greater than or equal to the Social Security and Medicare surplus will prevent Democrats from increasing spending. Democrats, by contrast, expect to use the tool of the lock box to restrain Republicans from their congenital urges to return money back to taxpayers.

Unfortunately, the argument between Republicans and Democrats about the size of the surplus will mask the real issue: How do we restore the economy to economic growth? We should return from our trip to Never Never Land. Democrats should make their best case for more spending increases even if the lock box idea is jettisoned. Republicans should urge even larger tax reductions, perhaps even reductions in the Social Security and Medicare taxes, despite decreasing nominal surpluses.

Feeling Good About ANWR

Sunday, August 19th, 2001

Many arguments in politics revolve around more than the merits of the issue at hand. Some issues serve as symbols or metaphors for other, broader themes. When an issue grows into a metaphor, it often means that clear and dispassionate thought about it will forever be impossible, lost in ardent rhetoric. The question of oil and gas exploration and drilling in the Artic National Wildlife Reserve (ANWR) may be one such issue.The entire reserve extends over 20 million acres, roughly the land area of South Carolina. The area that is required for oil and gas development is about 2000 acres, roughly the size of Dulles Airport in the suburbs of Washington DC. This is far smaller than a ranch owned by left-wing billionaire Ted Turner.

The well-respected, left-of-center magazine, the New Republic has briefly come over from the Dark Side and recognized the disingenuousness of the fight against drilling in ANWR. In the words of the New Republic editors:

“From the wailing and rending of garments that has followed the House of Representatives vote last week to allow ANWR exploration, you’d think environmentalists had good evidence that drilling for oil and gas would ecologically devastate the…Arctic tundra. They don’t.”

Contrary to visions of dead caribou, decades of experience with oil development on the North Slope of Alaska shows only minor instances of environmental damage. The caribou population has actually increased since oil and gas development began.What the editors of the New Republic did not see was that the vision of the decimation of caribou herds now galloping across the tundra was an image that Democrats in Congress wanted to firmly attach to George Bush. Democrats want George Bush to be depicted at as a callous oil-and-gas-man who would be happy to cover Yellowstone Park in a forest of oil derricks if it would make money for his oil friends. Any correspondence of their charges about ANWR to the truth would only be a happy coincidence. Imagery and symbolism were paramount, careful analysis irrelevant.

The editors of the New Republic instead encouraged Democrats to concentrate on what they consider a far more important issue, the Corporate Average Fuel Economy (CAFE) standards, standard to increase the fuel efficiency of cars. Forget about a tiny area in Alaska, the editors argue. It is more important to apply much stricter fuel economy standards to the dreaded Sport Utility Vehicle (SUV). Presently, SUVs are considered trucks and are not subject to the fuel economy standards applicable to cars.

Now CAFE standards are one of those minor issues that make people feel virtuous about supporting. The feeling of virtuousness is a commodity that is in shorter supply than oil. The standards may on balance be salutary, but they do not reduce fuel consumption and pollution as much as people might wish to believe. As stricter CAFE standards are implemented, new cars become more expensive. This increased cost encourages people to hang onto to their older, more fuel-inefficient and polluting automobiles, with precisely the opposite effect that was intended. In addition, when people do eventually buy fuel-efficient cars, their costs of operation drop and people become more likely to drive farther. They choose, for example, to drive for a family vacation rather than fly. This again circumvents the original intention of the legislation.

Moreover, increased fuel economy is often achieved by reducing vehicle weight. A recent report by the National Academy of Sciences concludes that this weight reduction probably increases the number of injuries to and deaths of drivers and passengers. This puts supporters of increased CAFE standards in the same camp as manufacturers of Firestone tires. Listening to some environmentalists arguing that reducing car size does not impact safety, one gets the eerie, deja vu feeling that environmentalists employ the same spokes-people as tobacco companies.

If reducing fuel consumption and associated pollution is really the goal, then increase the price of gasoline through taxes. The pricing mechanism is the most efficient way to reduce consumption. Of course, this policy would not be popular. A substantial increase in taxes would make explicit the cost of doing with less oil. Taxpayers would be constantly reminded of this cost every time they fill up. Instead, Democrats would rather hide the costs (even at the expense of more fuel consumption) in the price of new cars.

But then again it is the symbolism that is important. CAFE standards can fail to meet their lofty objectives, but the real point is for Democrats to pat themselves on the back in moral self-congratulations about our concern for Mother Earth. God knows that Democrats have recently had far too little to feel morally superior about.

The Day of Reckoning

Sunday, August 5th, 2001

“I am a firm believer in the people. If given the truth, they can be depended upon to meet any national crisis. The great point is to bring them the real facts.” — Abraham Lincoln.

There are two important dates that dominate the debate on the future of the Social Security System: 2016 and 2038. At present, Social Security receipts exceed the amount required to pay benefits to current retirees. The excess funds go to the Social Security Trust Fund, essentially government IOUs. In 2016, as more of the baby boom generation retires, Social Security receipts will be inadequate to cover the outflow of benefits. By 2032, the youngest cohort of the baby boomers will finally be retiring. Projections indicate that by 2038 the total paid out in excess of receipts will exceed the amount presumably accumulated in the Social Security Trust Fund. Those who choose to deliberately ignore inevitable Social Security short falls suggest that we have nothing to worry about since the day of reckoning is two generations away. The truth is otherwise.Essentially, the Social Security Trust Fund is a contrivance where one part of the government gives another part of the government an IOU without changing the net obligations of government. During the hearings held by the President’s Commission to Strengthen Social Security a useful analogy was drawn explaining this accounting chicanery.

Imagine a person attempting to save money towards his own retirement. Let us call him Joe. Assume that Joe has difficulty in maintaining the necessary discipline for retirement savings. Joe spends current income on current expenses and maybe even pays down his credit card debt a bit. To maintain his retirement fund, Joe writes himself IOUs. He, after all, has good credit. He trusts himself. When Joe retires he has a handful of IOUs to himself. However, the only way to redeem these IOUs is for Joe to generate current income. This is no different than if Joe had not bothered to conjure up the fiction of IOUs at all.

By analogy, the only way the government can pay future retirees once Social Security revenues exceed outlays is to reduce liability or increase income. Reducing benefits, increasing taxes, borrowing money, or all three can accomplish this. The year of reckoning is 2016, give or take a year or two, not 2038. For those who are 50 years old today, Social Security will begin to lack funds to meet benefit payments when they begin retirement. There is not much time for these people to make adjustments.

The longer we take to make adjustments to the system, the more wrenching the inevitable changes will be. Under the current Social Security structure, the average two-earner couple will have to pay an additional $860 per year to meet the Social Security shortfall in 2020. The amount grows to $2,100 by 2030. If the annual short fall is met by decreases in benefits alone, in 2020, a couple would have to receive $2,227 lower annual benefits. By 2030, the benefits would fall by $4605. (Draft report of the President’s Commission to Strengthen Social Security, July 23, 2001.)

To reduce the unfunded obligations of government there are number of relatively painless steps that can be taken now.

  1. The consumer cost of living index over estimates the true changes in cost of living for the retired. Former Senator Patrick Moynihan suggests that reducing the cost of living adjustment by 1% (e.g. a 2% inflation increase if the inflation rate is 3%) would decrease long-term Social Security costs while maintaining benefits at the real current level.
  2. When the Social Security System was created, life expectancy was considerably lower. In the age of retirement were tagged to life expectancy, the age of maximum Social Security benefit would be over 70 years. If we gradually adjust the retirement age upward, working people would have time to adjust their retirement plans while the long-term instability in Social Security would be alleviated.
  3. We should means test Social Security benefits. There is little social good achieved by subsidizing the retirement of the very affluent with income from young working families. Over the last few decades, the major transfer of wealth has been from the young to the elderly.
  4. We need to allow individuals to elect to invest a portion (say 2% of 12%) of the income going to fund Social Security into private retirement accounts roughly comparable to 401(k) or 403(b) accounts. Future Social Security benefits for those who make such a decision would be proportionately reduced. Others could elect to remain fully vested in the Social Security System. Any current short fall in revenues could be at least partially offset by increasing the income level at which Social Security taxes apply.

Demographic changes are inevitable. In this century, a time is rapidly approaching when there will be only two workers for every retiree. Many Republicans are afraid to explicitly mention the costs involved in reforming the Social Security System so that it becomes actuarially sound. Many Democrats eschew the reform of Social Security so that they can maintain a club with which to beat Republicans over the head during elections.As a Democrat with a large mountain of political capital and in the last years of his second term, former President Bill Clinton was in an excellent position to begin the necessary reforms. He declined. It now remains to his successor to exercise the necessary leadership.

Gay Jesus on Campus

Sunday, June 3rd, 2001

The ascent of the doctrine of political correctness on college campuses has been well documented by Dinesh D’Souza in Illiberal Education: Political Correctness and the College Experience, Roger Kimball in Tenured Radicals: How Politics Has Corrupted Higher Education, and others. In a seminal work, The Closing of the American Mind, philosopher Allan Bloom provided the intellectual underpinning for the proposition that too often “higher education has failed democracy and impoverished the souls of today students.”

Their charter and nature ought to make universities intellectual free-fire zones where no idea is so repugnant, so inane, so unconventional or so brilliant that it cannot find a forum for expression. Freedom of inquiry and freedom of expression are necessary prerequisites of academic freedom.

Unfortunately, many universities, fearful that protected groups might have their exquisitely delicate sensitivities offended, have instituted speech codes. The courts have been fairly consistent in striking down these codes as violations of the First Amendment, so they are often disguised as anti-harassment policies.

Rather than championing free speech, much intellectual energy on campuses has been devoted to devising subtle ways of enabling the thought police, without overtly violating the First Amendment. The Left have turned the ethos on campuses upside down. Free inquiry has too often been replaced by a Liberal orthodoxy no less repressive in its own way, than the Catholic Church’s silencing of Galileo for his suggestion that the Earth revolved around the Sun. It is not realistic to hide behind the notion that feelings need to be protected. Civil debate about fundamental and important issues will often and ought to evoke profound discomfort. Protecting people from intellectual and emotional distress hinders intellectual and emotional growth.

However, there are certain groups that appear to deserve no respectful deference, and are so retrograde that offending and insulting their beliefs is not only tolerated but considered evidence of open-mindedness. One such group is Conservative Christians.

The Indiana University-Purdue University Fort Wayne is allowing performances of Terrence McNally’s play Corpus Christi on campus. The play is set in Corpus Christi, Texas, but is not a very subtle retelling of the story of Jesus Christ. One of the main themes is the baseless assertion that Christ and his disciples were practicing homosexuals. Although the play’s defenders suggest that the play is a respectful and sympathetic account of one man’s theology and not meant to offend, the play is deliberately provocative. One cannot use the dialogue “F*** God” and honestly contend that people will not be offended. The play represents bad history and morally corrupt theology that is deliberately offensive to many Christians. If you believe the reviews, it does not even represent good drama.

Chancellor Michael Wartell defends allowing the play’s performance as part of the university’s charter of academic freedom on campus. Blind squirrels sometimes happen upon a nut and in this case Wartell is correct. Foolish ideas have a necessary place on campus. However, would Wartell mount the same difficult barricades if the play were offensive to the gay community? Would Wartell allow the performance of a play on campus that portrayed Matthew Shepard, the gay man brutally murdered in Wyoming, in a negative light? I would not bet on it.

This incident makes clear the double standard with regard to free speech and academic freedom on college campuses. Some ideas are protected with admirable vigilance, while others are suppressed or even prohibited. If you are Conservative or Christian your ideas can be lampooned and ridiculed with impunity. If you are a member of a protected group and adhere to the conventional orthodoxy you are not even asked to feel uncomfortable. Ironically, in the long run, such treatment will toughen Conservatives; hone their arguments and ideology, while the intellectual muscles of the Left will atrophy from disuse. Ideas that require suppression to survive will in the long run be recognized for their vacuousness.

The Impact of Free Trade on the Soul

Saturday, May 5th, 2001

“…There are times when the sacrifice of [the benefits of free trade] is in the broader national interest, or in the interests of preserving some of the values that Americans see as their obligation to export to other, less fortunate nations.” — Irwin M. Stelzer, “The Limits of Free Trade,” The Weekly Standard, April 30, 2001.

The economic case for free and unfettered trade is already well made. Both economic evidence and theory strongly support the conclusion that free trade increases the economic well being of all participants. Much of the increase in wealth in the post WWII era and the post-Cold War period, in particular, were strongly tied to the protocols of free trade. There will certainly be people and industries that are dislocated by the discipline of economic competition. In aggregate, however, wealth is increased and resources are more efficiently utilized. However, economic efficiency and welfare are not the only values against which public policies ought to be weighed. Free trade is more an expedient than an ultimate value.

Domestic labor organizations argue against free trade citing the lack of worker protection in foreign countries, but many times such arguments are motivated less by a concern for foreign workers and more by a fear of competition from poorer people willing to work for less. The AFL-CIO does not spend much political effort fighting for workers’ rights in the Sudan. Sudanese workers are not a competitive threat to American workers.

There are legitimate concerns that different countries might have environmental restrictions that are less stringent than those in the US. Some argue that trade should be used as a lever to compel compliance with US standards. While there is merit in this concern, it must be balanced by the consideration that different countries in different stages of development might reasonably strike a different balance between economic growth and environmental concerns.

In an ironic way, trade restrictions can reasonably be used as leverage to persuade countries to open up their markets. Imposing trade restrictions on countries that erect walls around their markets will mean that in the short run both the US and the other countries will be less well off. However, if such a policy opens up trade, short-term trade restrictions might prove salutary in the long run. However, sometimes even this argument degrades into an excuse for old-fashioned protectionism.

Free trade true believers argue that such trade encourages different countries to become more like us under the implicit assumption that being like us is a good thing. As free trade helps countries become wealthier, they will generally increase both worker and environmental protections. From a political standpoint, the economic discipline of free trade encourages a stable and open legal regime to mediate contractual disputes. The competition caused by free trade forces countries and companies to become more transparent and to loosen up the flow of information, which undermines repressive regimes.

However, the converse is also true. As we trade with other countries we may become, for better or worse, like them. Edwin Black recently published a book entitled, IBM and the Holocaust: The Strategic Alliance Between Nazi Germany and America’s Most Powerful Corporation. The book charges that IBM tabulating machines sold the IBM subsidiary Dehomag were used in the 1933 to 1939 censuses to create a cross-referenced data base of names, addresses, and family histories the Nazis used in implementing their Final Solution. The information from the censuses made the Nazi extermination of Jews more thorough in Germany than in occupied countries. (See Beatty, Jack, “Hitler’s Willing Business Partners,” Atlantic Monthly, April 4, 2001.)

In the 1930s there were already reports of anti-Semitic repression in Nazi Germany, evidence that was overlooked by IBM (and other US companies). The promise of profits made it easier to deliberately overlook inconvenient information. Hitler awarded Thomas J. Watson, the chairman of IBM, the Merit Cross of the Germany Eagle for his efforts.

Even if companies who are involved in trade are not active participants in repression, the promise of profits can cause these companies to avert their gaze from activities as varied as the anti-Semitism of the Nazi to the present day religious repression in the People’s Republic of China. Willingness to engage in trade with repressive regimes may in the long run compel repressive regimes to become less repressive, at least we can hope so. However, the long run can be a very long time and in the mean time our collective souls can be at risk.